EC 311 - Intermediate Microeconomics
2025
Chapter 4
Outline
Before we get into the math behind utity functions, let’s motivate what we want our economic models to do.
Preferences describe the subjective ranking that we put on different alternatives.
For example, my preference ranking of Eugene boba stores could go:
Tea 4
Bobahead
Day & Night
No boba
Rabbit Hole
What do you notice about the way I represented my preferences here?
This ranking is ordinal; I didn’t say how much more I like each thing, only which I like better
The ranking includes an outside option: No boba
Is it complete? Is there any place I’m missing?
The rational model of choice is the foundation of all economics.
Its axioms are that:
People have complete preferences
Those preferences are transitive
For convenience, we also usually add other assumptions, such as assuming “More is Better”
We say that preferences are always complete. So when comparing bundles A and B, you can always say one of the following:
I prefer A to B (\(A \succeq B\))
I prefer B to A (\(B \succeq A\))
I am indifferent between A and B (\(A \sim B\))
This allows us to compare and order any pair of bundles
Preferences are transitive. This means that when comparing bundles A, B, and C you can get logical orderings through rankings:
What would this graph mean?
All bundles are preferred equally!
Or at least more is no worse than less
In general, if a good is desirable we will want more of it
Imagine the market for coffee on campus
Additionally, imagine that the only other good that can be purchased is boba
On a basic level, demand for coffee is derived from individual’s choosing how to divide their income between coffee and boba
This is the problem we will be dealing with through the first half of the course
How does an individual allocate a finite amount of resources between two goods?
Note: There are clearly more than just two goods out there, so how can this be useful?
The main critique I always hear about economics courses is that they’re unrealistic. That’s mostly true, but we can learn about the aggregate by simplifying and making assumptions
We will frame the decisions as a two-good model where you may choose between:
The key takeaway here is that we can frame many important choices as “two-good” decisions
Consumption of any single good has two parts:
How it BENEFITS the consumer
What it COSTS the consumer
Let’s see what this means through a 1-good example \(\rightarrow\) Beer
Imagine the following scenario:
Number of Beers | Overall Level of Happiness | Change in Level of Happiness |
---|---|---|
0 | 0 | - |
1 | 10 | 10 |
2 | 25 | 15 |
3 | 35 | 10 |
4 | 40 | 5 |
5 | 42 | 3 |
6 | 30 | -12 |
If beer were free, how many beers should this person drink?
\[5\]
Now recall that beer costs $4, how many beers should this person drink?
\[4\]
You cannot simply find the consumption amount that makes you the happiest. But why?
The goal is to maximize your utility whilst acknowledging you have constraints
The choice is simple: consume an additional unit until the cost of doing so outweighs the benefit
Commit this idea to memory: it is the crux of economics and drives everything we will be doing
We maximize utility up to the point that it does not make sense to do so
Number of Beers | Overall Level of Happiness | Change in Level of Happiness |
---|---|---|
0 | 0 | - |
1 | 10 | 10 |
2 | 25 | 15 |
3 | 35 | 10 |
4 | 40 | 5 |
5 | 42 | 3 |
6 | 30 | -12 |
Some Questions:
We found two important values:
The additional benefit gained for an added unit of consumption
The additional cost paid for an added unit of consumption
We can describe the decision-making process in a more formal manner:
Ask yourself: Why must they be equal?
What matters for choice is the marginal benefit of an additional beer
In other words, what matters is the change in utility that occurs as we move to the right on the graph
Recall: A change in \(y\) as \(x\) increases is the derivative
The derivative of this function is the marginal benefit of beer
This is why derivatives are important
We can use derivatives to figure out the optimal amount to consume
Recall: The optimal choice is the point where MB = MC
The MC = 4. So we would choose the quantity of beers where MB = 4
The utility function of beer we’ve been using is:
\[U(x) = -x^{2} + 12x\]
Let’s practice: What would the optimal consumption amount be if the cost of beer is $2?
Find the Marginal Benefit
\[ MU_{x} = \dfrac{\partial U}{\partial x} = -2x + 12 \]
Set the MB equal to MC
\[\begin{align*} MB &= MC \\ -2x + 12 &= 2 \\ 2x &= 10 \\ x &= 5 \end{align*}\]
One key proposition of rationality is that we can represent preferences by real numbers.
A utility function maps a choice to a single number.
For example, let \(u(.)\) be the utility function from emoji to utils
I can have \(u(🍺) =5\), \(u(🌯)=10\), \(u(🤸)=25\)
I can also have \(u(🍺 \ , 🌯) = 20\), \(u(🍺 \ , 🌯 \ , 🤸) = 15\)
Cardinal: amounts which can be measured in meaningful units are cardinal numbers
Ordinal: all that matters is the relative ranking
The beer example was fairly straightforward. But we will be dealing with making choices between two goods.
Before we dive in, a couple of things to consider are:
A Utility Function is a function of two variables:
\[U = f(x,y)\]
Some facts:
For Example:
\[U = f(K,H) = 10K + 2H\]
\[U = f(K,H) = 10K + 2H\]
For a function of two variables there are two slopes
In the kombucha (K) and hop water (H) example we will have:
What are the Marginal Utilities of kombucha and hop water?
Now find the Marginal Utilities for Peanut Butter and Jelly
\[U = f(P,J) = P^{2} \cdot J\]
Peanut Butter
\[\begin{align*} MU_{P} &= 2P^{2-1} \cdot J = 2PJ \\ \end{align*}\]
Jelly
\[\begin{align*} MU_{J} &= P^{2} \cdot J^{1-1} = P^{2} \\ \end{align*}\]
They help us represent how people feel about goods \(x\) and \(y\)
There are certain properties that help us determine:
Do I like or dislike \(x\)?
Does how much I like \(x\) depend on how much \(x\) I already have?
Does how much I like \(x\) depend on how much \(y\) I have?
We can understand these properties by looking at the marginal utilities!
If I consume more \(x\), how does my utility move?
Beyond graphing the utility function, we need to find a way to answer this formally and mathematically
We can look at the sign of the derivative
Positive
I like \(x\)
Negative
I dislike \(x\)
Given my utility curve for kombucha (K) and hop water (H), what do I like or dislike?
\[U = f(K,H) = 10K + 2H\]
I like kombucha
\[MU_{K} = 10 > 0\]
I like hop water
\[MU_{H} = 2 > 0\]
Remember to think at the margin
Is each additional unit of \(x\) bring me more, less, or equal happiness as the previous unit?
This is slightly trickier to figure out, but we still use marginal utility logic
In fact, we will use what is called the Second Derivative
Mathematically, this is the derivative of \(MU_{x}\) w.r.t. \(x\) and we ask:
My utility for Cookies and Milk:
\[U = f(C,M) = C^{1/2}M^{1/2}\]
Cookies
\(MU_{c} = \dfrac{1}{2} \cdot C^{-1/2} \cdot M^{1/2}\) \(MU_{cc} = \dfrac{-1}{2} \cdot \dfrac{1}{2} \cdot C^{-1/2 - 1} \cdot M^{1/2}\) \(MU_{cc} = \dfrac{-1}{4} \cdot \dfrac{1}{C^{3/2}} \cdot M^{1/2}\) \(MU_{cc} = \dfrac{-M^{1/2}}{4C^{3/2}}\)
Milk
\(U_{mm} = \dfrac{-C^{1/2}}{4M^{3/2}}\)
\(MU_{cc}\) is negative so we can say that Cookies have a Decreasing Marginal Utility
This one is more straightforward: Does the marginal utility of \(x\) depend on \(y\)?
Mathematically, we take the derivative of \(MU_{x}\) w.r.t. to \(y\), and vice-versa.
Notationally, we have: \(MU_{xy}\)
Where we can determine the order of derivatives by looking at the subscript:
How about this utility for Peanut Butter and Jelly
\[U = f(P,J) = P^{2} \cdot J\]
Peanut Butter
\[\begin{align*} MU_{P} &= 2P^{2-1} \cdot J = 2PJ \\ MU_{PJ} &= 2P \cdot J^{1-1} = 2P \end{align*}\]
Jelly
\[\begin{align*} MU_{J} &= P^{2} \cdot J^{1-1} = P^{2} \\ MU_{JP} &= P^{2} = 2P \end{align*}\]
Notice that the cross-partials are the same and this will always be the case for any utility function!
What are Utility Functions?
Let’s consider Homework and Pizza
First, we decide whether the good is desirable (good) or undesirable (bad)
Note: This implies that the marginal utilities are \(MU_{H} < 0\) and \(MU_{P} > 0\)
Homework is a bad and Pizza is a good
Let’s also set the following requirements:
The marginal disutility of homework is larger when I have more of it
\(MU_{H}\) is decreasing in \(H \; \rightarrow \;\) We need an \(H\) in \(MU_{H}\)
The marginal utility of pizza is smaller when I have more of it
\(MU_{P}\) becomes smaller as I have more \(P \; \rightarrow \;\) We need an \(H\) in \(MU_{H}\)
\(MU_{P}\) does not depend on homework \(MU_{P}\) does not have an \(H\)
Attempt creating a utility function with the above characteristics
Here’s my version:
\[U(H,P) = -H^{2} + ln(P)\]
Now let’s prove that it meets the requirements
Homework is a bad and must be worse the more I have of interested
\[MU_{H} = -2H < 0\]
\[MU_{HH} = -2 <0\]
Pizza is a good, I get less joy from it the more I have, and it does not depend on how much homework I have
\[MU_{P} = \dfrac{1}{P} > 0 \]
\[MU_{PP} = \dfrac{-1}{P^{2}} < 0\]
\[MU_{PH} = 0 = MU_{HP}\]
The single most important property of a utility function is that we can measure the relative preference for one good over the other
We can measure how many units of \(y\) would you give up to get one more unit of \(x\)?
\[MRS = \dfrac{MU_{x}}{MU_{y}}\]
Here we are talking about the relative preference of \(x\) over \(y\), but how?
Consider \(U = f(x,y) = 4x + 2y\)
You get 4 units of utility for each \(x \; \rightarrow \; 4\)
You get 2 units of utility for each \(y \; \rightarrow \; 2\)
We can say that each \(x\) is twice as valuable as each \(y\)
Using our MRS formula we have:
\[MRS = \dfrac{MU_{x}}{MU_{y}} = \dfrac{4}{2} = 2\]
In Economics, we mainly deal with 4 types of functions, each with its set of properties and tricks
Cobb-Douglas
Quasi-linear
Perfect Substitutes
Perfect Complements
\[U(x,y) = x^{a}y^{b}\]
Find the MRS of this general function
\[MRS = \dfrac{MU_{x}}{MU_{y}} = \dfrac{ax^{a-1}y^{b}}{bx^{a}y^{b-1}} = \dfrac{a}{b} \cdot \dfrac{x^{a-1-a}}{y^{b-1-b}} = \dfrac{a}{b} \cdot \dfrac{x^{-1}}{y^{-1}} = \dfrac{a}{b} \cdot \dfrac{y}{x}\]
The MRS for a Cobb-Douglas will always look like
\[\dfrac{a}{b} \cdot \dfrac{y}{x}\]
\[MRS = \dfrac{a}{b} \cdot \dfrac{y}{x}\]
The MRS is a ratio of \(y\) to \(x\), multiplied by a constant
MRS is your willingness to trade \(y\) for \(x\)
As you get more \(x\), the MRS goes down
As you get more \(y\), the MRS goes up
\[U(x,y) = x^{3}y^{1/2}\]
Find the MRS of this utility function
\[MRS = \dfrac{MU_{x}}{MU_{y}} = \dfrac{3x^{2}y^{1/2}}{1/2x^{3}y^{-1/2}} = \dfrac{3}{1/2} \cdot \dfrac{y^{1/2}y^{1/2}}{x^{3}x^{-2}} = 6 \cdot \dfrac{y}{x}\]
If we recall that \(MRS = \dfrac{a}{b} \cdot \dfrac{y}{x}\) then we can take a shortcut:
\[MRS = \dfrac{a}{b} \cdot \dfrac{y}{x} \rightarrow \dfrac{3}{1/2} \cdot \dfrac{y}{x} = 6 \cdot \dfrac{y}{x}\]
\[U(x,y) = a \cdot ln(x) + b \cdot y\]
Where \(a \cdot ln(x)\) is the “quasi” part and \(b \cdot y\) is the “linear” part
Find the MRS of this general function
\[MRS = \dfrac{MU_{x}}{MU_{y}} = \dfrac{a/x}{b} = \dfrac{a}{b} \cdot \dfrac{1}{x}\]
\[MRS = \dfrac{a}{b} \cdot \dfrac{1}{x}\]
The MRS is a constant times \(1/x\)
As you get more \(x\), the MRS decreases
As you get more \(y\), the MRS remains the same
\[U(x,y) = 1/3 \cdot ln(x) + y\]
Find the MRS of this utility function
\[MRS = \dfrac{MU_{x}}{MU_{y}} = \dfrac{1/3 \cdot 1/x}{1} = \dfrac{1}{3} \cdot \dfrac{1}{x}\]
Using our shortcut we get:
\[MRS = \dfrac{a}{b} \cdot \dfrac{1}{x} = \dfrac{1/3}{1} \cdot \dfrac{1}{x} = \dfrac{1}{3} \cdot \dfrac{1}{x}\]
\[U(x,y) = a \cdot x + b \cdot y\]
Find the MRS of this general function
\[MRS = \dfrac{MU_{x}}{MU_{y}} = \dfrac{a}{b}\]
\[U(x,y) = 6x + \dfrac{1}{2} y \]
Find the MRS of this utility function
\[MRS = \dfrac{MU_{x}}{MU_{y}} = \dfrac{6}{1/2} = 12\]
And our shortcut shows:
\[MRS = \dfrac{6}{1/2} = 12\]
\[U(x,y) = \min \{a \cdot x, b \cdot y \}\]
This utility function requires a different form of intuition
Let’s first think of a simple example:
Imagine we are trying to make some hot chocolate which requires 1 pack of chocolate powder and 12 oz of milk
\[U(x,y) = \min \{1 \, choco, 12oz \, milk \}\]
You check your kitchen and find that there are 3 packs of chocolate powder and you have 15 oz of milk in your fridge
How many hot chocolates can we make?
These are goods that have to be consumed together in an exact proportion in order to produce any utility
There is no MRS, so we use a property called the No-Waste Condition:
\[U(x,y) = \min \{a \cdot x, b \cdot y \}\]
\[a \cdot x = b \cdot y\]
MRS is not defined (We cannot take a derivative)
We can use the No-Waste Condition:
When \(a \cdot x < b \cdot y\) you will give up any \(y\) you can to get more \(x\)
When \(a \cdot x > b \cdot y\) you will give up any \(x\) you can to get \(y\)
\[U(x,y) = \min \{ \dfrac{x}{2}, \dfrac{y}{4} \}\]
Find the No-Waste Condition of this utility function
No-Waste Condition is \(\dfrac{x}{2} = \dfrac{y}{4} \rightarrow 4x = 2y \rightarrow 2x = y\)
We can say:
If \(2x > y \; \rightarrow \;\) Too much \(x\), so we would trade some \(x\) for some \(y\)
If \(2x < y \; \rightarrow \;\) Too much \(y\), so we would trade some \(y\) for some \(x\)
When you have a utility function of two goods, any given combination of those two goods is called a Bundle
Take the following utility function and bundles
\[U(x,y) = x^{2}y\]
Bundle 1 is (3,2)
\[\begin{align*} U(3,2) &= 3^{2} \cdot 2 \\ &= 9 \cdot 2 = 18 \end{align*}\]
Bundle 2 is (1,0)
\[\begin{align*} U(1,0) &= 1^{2} \cdot 0 \\ &= 1 \cdot 0 = 0 \end{align*}\]
We will use the following axioms about preferences between bundles to ensure logical consistency
These come from economic theory so they will help you think like an economist but do not think this tells us how people behave
We are attempting to successfully predict behavior, so we will simply assume that everyone behaves accordingly
All of these are necessary to understand utility funcitons and be able to graph them
To do so we first need to learn about Indifference Curves
It is exactly what it sounds like
For example, for the utility of \(U(x,y) = 2x + 3y\) I am indifferent between bundles (3,2) and (0,4)
\[\begin{align*} U(3,2) &= 2(3) + 3(2) = 6 + 6 = 12 \\ \\ U(0,4) &= 2(0) + 3(4) = 12 \end{align*}\]
Given a utility function and a level of utility, you can find a whole set of bundles that you are indifferent between
For example, let \(U(x,y) = x + y\) and set \(U = 10\). Then we can find an infinite set of \(x\) and \(y\) that will give us our stated utility level
\[\begin{align*} x &= 10 \\ x &= 9 \\ x &= 8 \\ &. \\ &. \\ &. \end{align*}\]
\[\begin{align*} y &= 0 \\ y &= 1 \\ y &= 2 \\ &. \\ &. \\ &. \end{align*}\]
We can create a function that helps us find ALL possible bundles that make you indifferent at a given utility level
We call this an Indifference Curve
For our previous utility function \(U(x,y) = x + y\) where \(U = 10\), we solve for \(y\) and get:
\[\begin{align*} U(x,y) &= x + y \\ \\ 10 &= x + y \\ \\ 10 - x &= y \rightarrow \text{Indifference Curve (IC)} \end{align*}\]
\[U(x,y) = xy \;\; \text{where} \; U = 16\]
What type of Utility Function is this?
What is the associated Indifference Curve?
\[16 = xy \rightarrow y = \dfrac{16}{x} \rightarrow \text{ IC }\]
So why do we care about these curves?
Each utility function has a unique shape that we will learn
\[U(x,y) = 3x + y \; \text{ with } \; U = 6, \, 9, \, 15\]
First, find the indifference curves for each Utility value
\[U = 6\]
\[y = 6 - 3x\]
\[U = 9\]
\[y = 9 - 3x\]
\[U = 15\]
\[y = 15 - 3x\]
Next, we graph these functions
\[U(x,y) = \min \{ x, \dfrac{y}{2} \} \; \text { with } U = 2, \, 8, \, 9\]
Find the indifference curves for each utility value
\[U = 2\]
\[x = 2 \; \text{ or } y = 4\]
\[U = 8\]
\[x = 8 \; \text{ or } y = 16\]
\[U = 9\]
\[x = 9 \; \text{ or } y = 18\]
Next, we graph these functions
\[U(x,y) = x^{1/2}y \; \text{ with } U = 4, \, 8, \, 10\]
Find the indifference curves for each utility value
\[U = 4\]
\[y = \dfrac{4}{x^{1/2}}\]
\[U = 8\]
\[y = \dfrac{8}{x^{1/2}}\]
\[U = 10\]
\[y = \dfrac{10}{x^{1/2}}\]
Next, we graph these functions
\[U(x,y) = ln(x) + y \; \text{ with } U = 5, \, 15, \, 20\]
Find the indifference curves for each utility value
\[U = 5\]
\[y = 5 - ln(x)\]
\[U = 15\]
\[y = 15 - ln(x)\]
\[U = 20\]
\[y = 20 - ln(x)\]
Next, we graph these functions
It is very important that you understand the intuition behind indifference curves
Let’s view an example that can help:
Consider Weather Reports:
On cold days, what the weather feels like is a function of:
Temperature
Windchill
If windchill \(\downarrow\) then temperature \(\uparrow\)
We use this exact same logic for utility between two goods
Intuitively, if I want to stay at the same level of happiness as I lose some \(y\), what must happen to \(x\)?
This is why we read them from left to right and why they have a negative slope
All of the stuff from before can be formalized into the following 3:
ICs always go from the top left to the bottom right without changing direction
Additionally, this helps us visualize two important sets of bundles
This is the expected behavior of ICs. There are infinitely many, each representing a unique level of Utility
If ICs cross, they are contradictions
A balanced combination of two goods are preferred to extreme outcomes
Recall the Better-than-set
I drew Cobb-Douglas curves (mostly because they’re easier to illustrate these properties) but what about Perfect Complements or Perfect Substitutes?
Perfect Complements
Perfect Substitutes
Let’s look at the board again
Recall the intuition of what a movement along the indifference curve means:
This Marginal Rate of Substition (MRS) thing is pretty important
First, why is the slope the negative MRS?
The Indifference Curve slope is all about keeping the utility level constant while we move \(x\) and \(y\) in opposite directions
Therefore the IC slope = -MRS
For
\[U(x,y) = ax + by\]
\[\begin{align*} MRS &= \dfrac{MU_{x}}{MU_{y}} = \dfrac{a}{b} \\ -MRS &= \dfrac{-a}{b} \end{align*}\]
\[\begin{align*} \bar{U} &= ax + by \\ \bar{U} - ax &= by \\ \dfrac{\bar{U}}{b} - \dfrac{ax}{b} &= y \end{align*}\]
\[\text{Slope is the derivative! } \rightarrow \;\; \dfrac{\partial y}{\partial x} = \dfrac{-a}{b}\]
From this lecture you have learned:
Everything about utility functions and how to use them to find an MRS
Everything about Indifference Curves and how the IC slope relates to the MRS
The MRS is going to be key to solving utility maximization problems
Mathematically (Using derivatives)
Graphically (Drawing ICs)
However, when we maximize utility functions we have constraints, we called these Budget Constraints
Economic Theory says that individuals make themselves as happy as they possibly can, after choosing from a set of all bundles they can afford
Inside a budget constraint we use the exact same variables we use in our utility function, namely \(x\) and \(y\)
But we’ll need to introduce some new notation and terminology:
The price of good \(x \; \rightarrow \; P_{x}\)
The price of good \(y \; \rightarrow \; P_{y}\)
Your income, budget, or money-on-hand \(\rightarrow \; M\)
Putting together our variables we get our Budget Constraint
\[P_{x} \cdot x + P_{y} \cdot y \leq M\]
Do not let the inequality \(\leq\) scare you, it just means we can spend less than our total income
However, in our applications we are going to treat it as a strict equality
\[P_{x} \cdot x + P_{y} \cdot y = M\]
And let’s think why?
But do we usually spend all of our money?
Of course not, but here is how to think about it in the economics sense:
When you go to the grocery store you make to choices before even stepping inside:
How much to spend at the store
What to spend it on
First, we need our two goods from before: Beer (\(B\)) and Soda (\(S\))
Let’s label everything properly:
\(B = \text{Beer}\)
\(S = \text{Soda}\)
\(P_{B} = \$4\)
\(P_{S} = \$2\)
\(M = \$20\)
What does the Budget Constraint look like?
\[B \cdot P_{B} + S \cdot P_{S} = M\]
\[4B + 2P = 20\]
We graph the budget in the same space in as our IC, but what are we graphing?
\[P_{x} \cdot x + P_{y} \cdot y = M\]
And thankfully, this is just a straight line
\[P_{x} \cdot x + P_{y} \cdot y = M\]
Thinking intuitively, this graph represents:
\[\begin{align*} P_{x} \cdot x + P_{y} \cdot 0 &= M \\ P_{x} \cdot x &= M \\ x &= \dfrac{m}{P_{x}} \end{align*}\]
Following the logic we just did, the budget line will connect two points:
One for when we buy only \(x\) and one for when we buy only \(y\)
\[(\dfrac{M}{P_{x}}, 0) \text{ and } (0, \dfrac{M}{P_{y}})\]
The Budget Constraint is the line:
\[y = \dfrac{M}{P_{y}} - \dfrac{P_{x}}{P_{y}} \cdot x \;\; \text{ where the slope is } \; -\dfrac{P_{x}}{P_{y}}\]
Now, let’s define \[P_{x} = \dfrac{\$}{x} \text{ and } P_{y} = \dfrac{\$}{y}\]
We get this result in terms of units!
\[\dfrac{P_{x}}{P_{y}} = \dfrac{\$/x}{\$/y} = \dfrac{\$}{x} \cdot \dfrac{y}{\$} = \dfrac{y}{x}\]
As we just saw, the price ratio \(P_{x}/P_{y}\) can be measured in units of \(x\) per units of \(y\)
We had already seen something that is measured in units \(\rightarrow\) the MRS
This leads us to understand the differences between the two:
Budgets are not static. Prices and income can change based on market conditions so it is important to understand the effects when factors change
We can have changes in income (increase or decrease)
Price of \(x\) can change (increase or decrease)
Price of \(y\) can change (increase or decrease)
Note - We normally consider what happens when only one of the possible factors change, and hold all others fixed
What happens to the budget if income \((M)\) increases?
\(\dfrac{M}{P_{x}}\), the maximum amount of \(x\) that can be purchased goes up
\(\dfrac{M}{P_{y}}\), the maximum amount of \(y\) that can be purchased goes up
The slope of the BC \((-P_{x}/P_{y})\) stays the same
Income changes affect the overall amount an individual can consume, but has no effect on the relative cost of the goods
Intuitively, the opposite is true if income \((M)\) decreases
What happens to the budget if the price of good \(x\) \((P_{x})\) increases?
The maximum amount of \(x\) that can be consumed goes down \((\dfrac{M}{P_{x}}) \downarrow\)
The maximum amount of \(y\) that can be consumed stays the same \((\dfrac{M}{P_{x}})\)
The price ratio \((- \dfrac{P_{x}}{P_{y}})\) becomes steeper
Once more, the opposite happens with a decrease
How about a shift in \(P_{y}\) ?
EC311 - Lecture 03 | Consumer Behavior