EC 311 - Intermediate Microeconomics
2025
Outline
Topics
Producer Theory Basics (6.1)
Cost Minimization Problems (6.4)
Returns to Scale (6.5)
This course boils down to two main things:
Consumers buy things
We call that Demand
We just slayed that beast
Firms make things
We call this Supply
We are about to meet this beast
Let’s determine the role of the firm
Firms produce goods (output) to sell consumers
To produce output, firms need factors of production (inputs) such as labor and capital
Firms use a production process (technology) to transform inputs into output
How firms choose to produce things is guided by a similar principle to how individuals consume things
Marginal Productivity
The impact of one additional factor of production on the total amount produced
Recall that utility is usually diminishing as consumption increases
Productivity also diminishes as a firm uses more inputs
We will begin by making a simplifying assumption to make our lives easier
Firms will have 2 typical inputs
Labor (L) \(\Rightarrow\) Workers
Capital (K) \(\Rightarrow\) Factory space, equipment, hardware, etc.
Similar to the Budget Constraint from Consumer Theory, we can formalize the firm’s costs:
\[ \text{Costs:} \;\; w \cdot L + r \cdot K \]
Write the costs of a firm that faces a wage of $10 and a rental rate of $12:
\[ \text{Costs:} \;\; 10 L + 12 K \]
Instead of maximizing utility, as consumers do, firms will
MINIMIZE THEIR COSTS OF PRODUCTION
These decisions are also done under a constraint, but what constraints do firms face?
Let’s tell a story to see the logic before we jump into the math
Imagine you are the manager of a clothing factory that produces Ducks football jerseys
It is almost Fall and Mr. Nike himself calls you. They tell you “We need 20,000 jerseys made for the start of the season”
Your goal is to choose how many workers \((L)\) and how much capital \((L)\) to use to produce the 20,000 jerseys as cheaply as possible
How do you figure out how to use \(L\) and \(K\) to make 20,000 jerseys?
With a Production Function
These are a function of how a firm can transform inputs into outputs
It will work just like a utility function
\[\begin{align*} F(L,K) &= Q \\ F(L,K) &= 20,000 \end{align*}\]
The problem the factory manager solves can be written as
\[ \min \;\; w \cdot L + r \cdot K \;\;\; s.t. \;\;\; F(L,K) = Q = 20,000 \]
We can read this as:
Now let’s say we have the following values:
The problem becomes:
\[ \min \;\; 10L + 5K \;\;\; s.t. \;\;\; F(L,K) = 5L + 2K = 20,000 \]
The methods to solve these problems are practically the same as we saw in Consumer Theory
However, we need to re-label some things:
\[ \text{MRTS} = \frac{MP_{L}}{MP_{K}} = \frac{\frac{\partial F}{\partial L}}{\frac{\partial F}{\partial K}} = \frac{\text{Marginal Productivity of Labor}}{\text{Marginal Productivity of Capital}} \]
\[ \min \;\; 10L + 5K \;\;\; s.t. \;\;\; F(L,K) = 5L + 2K = 20,000 \]
The solution should look very familiar. We are trying to choose \(L^{*}\) and \(K^{*}\) that optimizes our productivity.
What type of production function is this?
Perfect Substitutes
Find MRTS and Set Equal to Price Ratio
\[\begin{align*} \text{MRTS} \;\; &? \;\; \text{Price Ratio} \\ \frac{MP_{L}}{MP_{K}} \;\; &? \;\; \frac{w}{r} \\ \frac{5}{2} \;\; &? \;\; \frac{10}{5} \\ \end{align*}\]
Interpret the MRTS and Price Ratio Relationship
\[ \text{MRTS} > \text{Price Ratio} \]
Use only Labor \(\; \rightarrow \; K^{*} = 0\)
Plug into Production Function
\[ K^{*} = 0 \; \Rightarrow \; F(L,K) = 20,000 \; \rightarrow \; 5L + 2(0) = 20,000 \; \rightarrow \; L^{*} = \frac{20,000}{5} = 4,000 \]
\[ \min \;\; 10L + 5K \;\;\; s.t. \;\;\; F(L,K) = 5L + 2K = 20,000 \]
What if \(\; w = 20 \;\) and \(\; r = 5 \;\)?
Find MRTS and Set Equal to Price Ratio
\[\begin{align*} \text{MRTS} \;\; &? \;\; \text{Price Ratio} \\ \frac{MP_{L}}{MP_{K}} \;\; &? \;\; \frac{w}{r} \\ \frac{5}{2} \;\; &? \;\; \frac{20}{5} \\ \end{align*}\]
Interpret the MRTS and Price Ratio Relationship
\[ \text{MRTS} < \text{Price Ratio} \]
Use only Capital \(\; \rightarrow \; L^{*} = 0\)
Plug into Production Function
\[ K^{*} = 0 \; \Rightarrow \; F(L,K) = 20,000 \; \rightarrow \; 5(0) + 2K = 20,000 \; \rightarrow \; K^{*} = \frac{20,000}{2} = 10,000 \]
We have the exact same functional forms that we used for utility functions
This is good news! It means that mathematically nothing should be suprising
We are just relabeling variables and using the same processes we already know
Identify and find the MRTS for the following Production Function
\[ F(L,K) = L^{1/3}K^{2/3} \]
\[ \text{MRTS} = \frac{MP_{L}}{MP_{K}} = \frac{1/3 \cdot L^{-2/3}K^{2/3}}{2/3 \cdot L^{1/3}K^{-1/3}} = \frac{1/3}{2/3} \cdot \frac{K^{2/3}K^{1/3}}{L^{1/3}L^{2/3}} = \frac{1}{2} \cdot \frac{K}{L} \]
We will deal with each functional form the same way as we did before.
Cobb-Douglas
Set MRTS equal to Price Ratio
This tells us the relationship that must hold between \(L\) and \(K\) (Optimality Conditions)
Plug Optimality into Production Function constraint
Quasi-linear
Set MRTS equal to Price Ratio
This tells you exactly how much of the input that is inside the \(ln()\) function to use
Plug Optimality into Production Function constraint
Perfect Complements
Perfect Substitutes
Compare the MRTS to the Price Ratio
\[ \min \;\; 10L + 5K \;\;\; s.t. \;\;\; F(L,K) = L \cdot K = 20,000 \]
Find the Optimal Values of Labor and Capital
Find MRTS and set it equal to Price Ratio
\[\begin{align*} \text{MRTS} &= \frac{w}{r} \\ \frac{K}{L} &= \frac{10}{5} = 2 \\ K^{*} &= 2L \end{align*}\]
Plug Optimality Condition into Production Function constraint
\[\begin{align*} L \cdot \color{red}{K^{*}} &= 20,000 \\ L \cdot \color{red}{2L} &= 20,000 \\ 2L^{2} &= 20,000 \\ L^{2} &= 10,000 \\ L^{*} &= \sqrt{10,000} \\ L^{*} &= 100 \\ \\ \end{align*}\]
Find Optimal Capital
\[K^{*} = 2 \cdot \color{red}{L^{*}} = 2 \cdot \color{red}{100} = 200\]
Let the firm’s production function be \(F(L,K) = L + 2K\). What are the cost minimizing \(L\) and \(K\) to produce 100 goods, when they face \(w = 10\) and \(r = 10\)
Find MRTS and Compare to Price Ratio
\[\begin{align*} \text{MRTS} &= \frac{w}{r} \\ \frac{MP_{L}}{MP_{K}} &= \frac{10}{10} \\ \frac{1}{2} &\lesseqgtr 1 \end{align*}\]
Determine which is greater
\[\begin{align*} \frac{1}{2} < 1 \end{align*}\]
Use only Capital \(\rightarrow L^{*} = 0\)
Plug into Production Function to Determine \(\; K^{*}\)
\[\begin{align*} F(L,K) &= Q \\ L^{*} + 2K^{*} &= 100 \\ 0 + 2K^{*} &= 100 \\ K^{*} &= 50 \end{align*}\]
Although the problem we are solving is essentially the same, the levers we are pulling are not
Let’s introduce some new (but familiar) concepts:
Production Functions have Isoquants instead of Indifference Curves
Isoquants are all the possible combinations of labor and capital that produce a certain level of output
Fortunately, they have the same shape as their Indifference Curves but instead of a level of Utility, they represent a level of quantity produced
Imagine that it takes exactly 20 minutes of labor (1/3 of an hour) AND 10 units of capital to make one Ducks Jersey
What form does this Production Function take?
Perfect Complements
The key difference is a conceptual one:
For consumers, we would maximize the Utility Function, where the costs acted as our constraint
For producers, we minimize the cost function and the production function is the constraint
We are looking for the lowest possible Isocost line that touches the production contraint exactly once
Some things have not changed
The largest mathematical difference between production and utility are Returns to Scale
With utility we were “measuring” units of happiness or utility
Production, however, is more easily measured:
One unit of production or \(Q\) can be:
A Ducks jersey
A Chocolate Bar
A car
Etc.
Returns to Scale will measure the following:
If I increase my inputs by equal amounts (such that labor and capital increase by some constant \(z\)), how much does my output increase by?
There are three possible outcomes:
Let’s say you run a small business where you make corndogs. You are currently employing 10 labor hours and 100 units of capital
All together, these inputs help you produce 20 Corndogs
Now you double your inputs, such that:
Decreasing Returns to Scale
As usual, we can show these concepts mathematically
\[ F(zL,zK) > z \cdot F(L,K) \]
\[ F(zL,zK) = z \cdot F(L,K) \]
\[ F(zL,zK) < z \cdot F(L,K) \]
Let your Production Function be \(F(L,K) = L^{2}K\) and you increase your inputs by some constant \(z\)
\[\begin{align*} F(zL,zK) &= (zL)^{2} \cdot zK \\ &= \color{red}{z^{2}}L^{2} \cdot \color{red}{z}K \\ &= \color{red}{z^{3}} \cdot L^{2} K \end{align*}\]
Compare this to what scaling your production function by \(\; z \;\) looks like
\[\begin{align*} z^{3} \cdot L^{2}K > z \cdot L^{2}K \end{align*}\]
We have Increasing Returs to Scale (IRS)
Let the Production Function be \(F(L,K) = L^{1/4}K^{3/4}\) and you increase your inputs by some constant \(z\)
Show what type of Returns to Scale you have
\[\begin{align*} F(zL,zK) &= (zL)^{1/4} (zK)^{3/4} \\ &= \color{red}{z^{1/4}}L^{1/4} \cdot \color{red}{z^{3/4}}K^{3/4} \\ &= \color{red}{z^{1/4}}\color{red}{z^{3/4}}L^{1/4}K^{3/4} \\ &= \color{red}{z} \cdot L^{1/4}K^{3/4} \end{align*}\]
Compare this to what scaling your production function by \(\; z \;\) looks like
\[\begin{align*} z \cdot L^{1/4}K^{3/4} = z \cdot L^{1/4}K^{3/4} \end{align*}\]
We have Constant Returns to Scale (CRS)
Let the Production Function be \(F(L,K) = L^{1/3}K^{1/2}\) and you increase your inputs by some constant \(z\)
Show what type of Returns to Scale you have
\[\begin{align*} F(zL,zK) &= (zL)^{1/3}(zK)^{1/2} \\ &= \color{red}{z^{1/3}}L^{1/3} \cdot \color{red}{z^{1/2}}K^{1/2} \\ &= \color{red}{z^{5/6}} \cdot L^{1/3}K^{1/2} \end{align*}\]
Compare this to what scaling your production function by \(\; z \;\) looks like
\[\begin{align*} z^{5/6} \cdot L^{1/3}K^{1/2} < z \cdot L^{1/3}K^{1/2} \end{align*}\]
We have Decreasing Returs to Scale (DRS)
Producers have a target quantity they must achieve
Their goal is to do so in the cheapest form possible using their inputs and their production technology
When choosing quantities, they are also aware of how much their inputs will cost them
All this together means that they will find the minimum cost line to achieve a target quantity of goods
EC311 - Lecture 05 | Production