EC 311 - Intermediate Microeconomics
2025
Outline
Topics
Cost Curves (7.3)
Average and Marginal Costs (7.4)
Our goal for the second half of the class is to minimize costs.
We will do this by deriving a minimzed cost function but what even is it?
Let’s begin by introducing some useful notation:
We will leverage this information:
Knowing \(C^{*}(Q)\) means that we do not have to solve the cost minimization problem to figure out how much it will cost you to produce a target quantity
The general formula for a cost function is:
\[ C^{*}(Q) = wL^{*}(Q) + rK^{*}(Q) \]
To find this we will
Last lecture we found levels of \(L^{*}\) and \(K^{*}\) when we knew \(Q\). Now we will keep \(Q\) as a variable so we can find costs for any possible quantity.
Let’s say we are faced with the following problem:
\[ \min 10L + 10K \;\;\;\; s.t. \;\;\;\; \bar{Q} = f(L,K) = L^{1/4}K^{1/4} \]
We begin by finding the MRTS and set it equal to the Price Ratio
MRTS
\[\begin{align*} \text{MRTS} &= \frac{MU_{L}}{MU_{K}} \\ &= \frac{1/4 \cdot L^{-3/4}K^{1/4}}{1/4 \cdot L^{1/4}K^{-3/4}} \\ &= \frac{K^{1/4}K^{3/4}}{L^{1/4}L^{3/4}} = \frac{K}{L} \\ \\ \end{align*}\]
Price Ratio
\[\begin{align*} \frac{w}{r} = \frac{10}{10} = 1 \end{align*}\]
Set Them Equal
\[\begin{align*} \frac{K}{L} = 1 \rightarrow K = L \end{align*}\]
\[ K = L \;\;\;\; \text{recall:} \;\; \bar{Q} = f(L,K) = L^{1/4}K^{1/4} \]
We found our Optimality Condition for \(K\) and \(L\)
Plug into Q-Constraint to find \(\; L^{*}(Q) \;\) and \(\; K^{*}(Q) \;\)
Q-Constraint
\[\begin{align*} Q &= F(L,K) = L^{1/4}\color{red}{K^{1/4}} \\ Q &= L^{1/4}\color{red}{L^{1/4}} = L^{1/2} \\ Q &= L^{1/2} \\ \end{align*}\]
Solve for \(\; L^{*}(Q) \;\) and \(\; K^{*}(Q)\)
\[\begin{align*} L^{1/2} &= Q \\ (L^{1/2})^{\color{red}{2}} &= Q^{\color{red}{2}} \\ L^{*} &= Q^{2} \\ K^{*} &= Q^{2} \end{align*}\]
\[ L^{*} = Q^{2} \;\;\; \& \;\;\; K^{*} = Q^{2} \;\;\;\; \text{recall:} \; C(Q) = 10L + 10K \]
We found our optimal Labor and Capital choices are in terms of \(Q\)
Find \(\; C^{*}(Q) \;\) using \(\; L^{*} \;\) and \(\; K^{*}\)
\[\begin{align*} C^{*}(Q) &= 10 \cdot \color{red}{L^{*}(Q)} + 10 \cdot \color{red}{K^{*}(Q)} \\ C^{*}(Q) &= 10 \cdot \color{red}{Q^{2}} + 10 \cdot \color{red}{Q^{2}} \\ C^{*}(Q) &= 20 \cdot Q^{2} \end{align*}\]
To begin, they are very useful in industry
Let’s think back to our Ducks jersey example. Nike wants you to make 20,000 jerseys. All you do is turn around and say it will cost
\[\begin{align*} C^{*}(Q) &= 20 \cdot Q^{2} \\ C^{*}(20,000) &= 20 \cdot 20,000^{2} \\ C^{*}(20,000) &= 20 \cdot 400,000,000 = 8,000,000,000 \end{align*}\]
But then with Bo Nix being gone, they only need 1,000 jerseys
So you say: That sucks, I thought we were better than just Bo, but okay. It’ll cost:
\[ C^{*}(1,000) = 20 \cdot 1,000^{2} = 20,000,000 \]
More generally, as the factory manager, you would just share your cost function with Nike and they can:
But before we can get into Profit Maximization, we will dive deeper into understanding cost functions
Beyond wages and rental rates, economists think about costs in a different way:
We consider ALL foregone alternatives that we could have used our resources in
We call this opportunity cost:
Let’s consider of a non-economics example Kyler Murray
NFL Quarterback for the AZ Cardinals
He has a 5yr/ $230,500,000 contract
But he also played baseball in college and nearly went pro
Knowing what is considered as costs in economics helps us with the theory part of production
For now, we can figure out how we expect cost functions to behave:
Assume a generic cost function such that \(C = F(Q)\)
When \(Q\) increases what do we expect to happen to \(C\)?
It usually costs more to make more goods
This means that the first derivative \((C'(Q))\) should be?
The derivative of \(C(Q)\) is very important
So much so that we give it a name: Marginal Cost (MC)
We will add an additional assumption to make our lives easier
Assume that firms production functions exhibit decreasing returns
Does it actually cost nothing to make nothing?
We will assume that there exists some form of overhead or fixed costs associated with producing goods
A good thinker is initially skeptical. So let’s cast some doubt on our Increasing Marginal Cost assumption
Isn’t producing in bulk sometimes much easier than producing small quantities?
So this is true, but only up to a point
We will be dealing with two types of cost functions: Quadratic and Cubic:
Quadratic
MC is always increasing
\[\begin{align*} C(Q) &= Q^{2} + 10 \\ \frac{\partial C(Q)}{\partial Q} &= MC = 2Q \\ \end{align*}\]
\[\begin{align*} \frac{\partial MC}{\partial Q} &= 2 > 0 \end{align*}\]
How Does the Graph Look?
Cubic
MC is initially decreasing, and eventually increasing
\[\begin{align*} C(Q) &= \frac{1}{3}Q^{3} - Q^{2} + 2Q + 12 \\ \frac{\partial C(Q)}{\partial Q} &= MC = Q^{2} - 2Q + 2 \end{align*}\]
\[\begin{align*} \frac{\partial MC}{\partial Q} &= 2Q - 2 \end{align*}\]
\[\begin{align*} 2Q - 2 &= 0 \\ 2Q &= 2 \\ Q &= 1 \end{align*}\]
When does it switch from (-) to (+)?
\[\begin{align*} Q &< 1 \rightarrow \text{Decreasing} \\ Q &> 1 \rightarrow \text{Increasing} \end{align*}\]
Up to now we have expressed firm’s costs as
\[ TC(Q) = w \cdot L^{*}(Q) + r \cdot K^{*}(Q) \]
Which let’s us know the cheapest way to produce a given target \(Q\)
We can also express costs as a function of quantity
\[ TC(Q) = f(Q) + F \]
Where \(F\) is a non-negative constant
We will split these costs up by type (i.e. More Cost Functions!)
Costs will fall into one of two categories:
Fixed Costs
Costs that are paid even if the firm produces nothing \(\rightarrow C(0)\)
Variable Costs
Costs that are increasing in the quantity produced (e.g. materials and labor used to produce each unit)
In its simplest form, total cost can be written as
\[ \text{Total Cost} = \text{Variable Costs} + \text{Fixed Costs} \]
These are costs the firm has to pay even if it produces 0 units of output
\[ FC = TC(0) = f(0) + F = F \]
We can find these by setting \(Q = 0\)
Find the Fixed Costs for the following Cost Function
\[ C(Q) = Q^{2} + 10 \]
\[ C(0) = 0^{2} + 10 = 10 \]
These are the increasing costs that the firm pays for every unit of quantity produced
\[\begin{align*} TC(Q) &= VC + FC \\ VC &= TC(Q) - FC \end{align*}\]
Find the Variable Costs for the following Cost Function
\[ C(Q) = Q^{2} + 10 \]
\[ VC = Q^{2} \]
It is always the case that
\[ C(Q) = VC(Q) + FC \]
Costs will always be the sum of the variable costs and the fixed cost
Let’s practice:
Decompose the following Cost Function into FC, VC, and MC
\[ C(Q) = \frac{1}{3} Q^{3} - Q^{2} + 2Q - 12 \]
\[\begin{align*} FC &= 12 \\ VC &= \frac{1}{3} Q^{3} - Q^{2} + 2Q \\ MC &= Q^{2} - 2Q + 2 \end{align*}\]
Although Total, Variable, and Fixed Costs are important to Cost Functions we do not really care for them on their own
What we care about are the Average of these costs
Now we will introduce Average Costs which are quite literally just the average of the previous costs
Average Total Costs
\[ ATC(Q) = \frac{C(Q)}{Q} \]
Average Fixed Costs
\[ AFC(Q) = \frac{FC}{Q} \]
Average Variable Costs
\[ AVC(Q) = \frac{VC(Q)}{Q} \]
For the following Cost Function
\[ C(Q) = Q^{2} + 10 \]
\[\begin{align*} ATC = Q + \frac{10}{Q} \;\;\;\;\;\;\;\;\;\; AFC = \frac{10}{Q} \;\;\;\;\;\;\;\;\;\; AVC = Q \end{align*}\]
Graphing cost functions is very helpful to understanding what is going on and how optimal choices are made
For the Cost Function
\[ C(Q) = \frac{1}{3}Q^{3} - Q^{2} + 2Q + 12 \]
We will graph the MC, AFC, AVC, and ATC
But first we will derive them
\[ C(Q) = \frac{1}{3}Q^{3} - Q^{2} + 2Q + 12 \]
The Marginal Cost
\[\begin{align*} MC &= \frac{\partial C(Q)}{\partial Q} = Q^{2} - 2Q + 2 \end{align*}\]
Graphing MC
\[ C(Q) = \frac{1}{3}Q^{3} - Q^{2} + 2Q + \color{red}{12} \]
The Average Fixed Cost
\[\begin{align*} AFC &= \frac{FC}{\partial Q} = \frac{12}{Q} \end{align*}\]
Graphing AFC
\[ C(Q) = \color{red}{\frac{1}{3}Q^{3} - Q^{2} + 2Q} + 12 \]
The Average Variable Cost
\[\begin{align*} AVC &= \frac{VC}{\partial Q} = \frac{1}{3}Q^{2} - Q + 2 \end{align*}\]
Graphing AVC
\[ C(Q) = \color{red}{\frac{1}{3}Q^{3} - Q^{2} + 2Q + 12} \]
The Average Total Cost
\[\begin{align*} ATC &= \frac{C(Q)}{Q} = \frac{1}{3}Q^{2} - Q + 2 \end{align*}\]
Graphing ATC
As always, the scale is not very important
But be sure to get the most important facts down:
What is so special about the point where MC and ATC cross?
Let’s look at an example that will show us what I mean intuitively
Imagine we measure the height of everyone in class and find the average height
Then someone new joins the class
What happens to the average height if the new person is shorter than the average?
It decreases
When the Marginal Person is shorter than the average, the average decreases
When the Marginal Person is taller than the average, the average increases
At our sweet spot where MC = ATC at the minimum of the ATC we can say:
Therefore, when MC = ATC, the average total cost is switching from decreasing to increasing
All of this will be useful for our next topic: Profit Maximization
EC311 - Lecture 06 | Cost Functions